Moscow as an Emergent World City: International Links, Business
Developments and the Entrepreneurial City**
Vladimir Kolossov*, Olga Vendina*, and
John O’Loughlin**
*Institute of Geography
Russian Academy of Sciences
Staromonetny per. 29
109017 Moscow,
Russia
Email: polgeogr@igras.geonet.ru
** Institute of Behavioral Science
University of Colorado at Boulder
Campus Box 487
Boulder, CO.
80309-0487, USA
Email: johno@colorado.edu
**Professor
Kolossov is Head of the Center of Geopolitical
Studies, Institute
of Geography, Russian
Academy of Sciences and Dr. Vendina
is a researcher in the Institute of Geography,
Russian Academy
of Sciences; Professor O’Loughlin is a Professor of Geography in the Institute
of Behavioral Science at the University
of Colorado, Boulder. This research was supported by a research
grant from the Russian Foundation for Fundamental Studies N 01-06-80157 to Vladimir
Kolossov and by a National Science Foundation (United
States) research grant to John
O’Loughlin. Comments on an earlier
version of the paper by Professor Beth Mitchneck, University
of Arizona at the Annual Meeting of
the Association of American Geographers in New York
and the research assistance at the University
of Colorado of Altinay
Kuchukeeva, Clionadh Raleigh and Tom Dickinson are gratefully
acknowledged.
Abstract
Using the “Informational City” concept of Manuel Castells and its
extension into the world-city literature, this paper examines contemporary
strategies of urban management in Moscow. The focus is on the international
communication trends that are transforming Moscow into an Informational City, manifested locally in the establishment of various types of
business districts. On the basis of
detailed data (local post offices zones) in Moscow, the location of diverse
business facilities, their restriction to particular types of urban
environments, their relation to the geography of government organization, and
the location of the financial sphere and trade (especially in luxury items) are
analyzed. Like other world cities, the
transformation of Moscow from a Soviet to an Informational City has produced a polarized city, one that increasingly that fits the “citadel-ghetto”
model. While a concerted effort of the
state, municipal authorities and private capital encourages the growth of
business districts, the interests of the majority of Moscovites
are ill served by the contemporary political structures and processes.
Russia's recent integration into the world economy
after 1991 in a time of market reforms and the dominance of Moscow in Russian
economic and political life have raised questions about the nature, causes and
rate of restructuring of the functions of the capital city. Central to these concerns are the trends and
prospects of Moscow's conversion into a world city that will maintain
the political and social stability required for continued Western
investment. While the economic crisis
of August 1998 set back the rapid integration of Moscow into the European and world systems of city
networks, the past few years have seen a rebound of the global external
linkages established in the increasingly-market economy of Russia. The
purpose of this paper is to examine the changes, both external and internal, in
the Moscow city economy and determine if the city is on a
sustainable path to status as a world city or whether Moscow remains the center of a network of cities that
are partially isolated from the rest of the world system. Evidence for both points of view can be
gleaned from the recent work of Peter Taylor and his Loughborough University colleagues on world city formation (Beaverstock et al., 2000; Fossaert,
2001; Taylor, 2000; Taylor and Hoyler, 2000). By gathering and analyzing recent data from
Russian sources, we can help to separate fact from fiction regarding economic
life in contemporary Moscow. Though Moscow is not a typical Russian city,
its trajectory points to the future for other large post-Soviet cities.
Since the move of the capital from St. Petersburg
to Moscow in 1918, the Russian capital has been both an industrial and
governmental center, first for the Soviet Union and from 1945-1991, for the
broader Communist bloc. During the Cold
War, Moscow’s links with the rest
of the world were spatially limited and highly constrained by political and
ideological considerations, a stark contrast to Western European cities. Since 1991, Moscow has re-entered the world
system as a linchpin of Western investment and economic activity in the former
Soviet Union and the economic profile of the city, as well as its streetscape,
has changed profoundly as a result.
Market reforms in Moscow,
embarked on the path of post-industrial development (Treivish,
Pandit and Bond, 1993) without a clear roadmap, have
revealed distinct characteristics of an “informational” city (Castells, 1989) as a stage on the way to "world city”
status. Signs of such an evolution have
included an office boom, visible in the rental prices and evident to all
residents and visitors by the proliferation of cranes and construction sites in
central Moscow (Vendina, 1997); the creation of an infrastructure of telecommunications, communications and urban
services, based upon technology; the
establishment of national-international
business centers; and a booming high-end retail sector in central Moscow
categorized by exclusive shopping centers and gallerias. A proliferation of joint ventures between
local and Western capitalists and the upgrading of the “kiosk” economy to a
more formal retail environment mark Moscow
as the urban leader of the post-communist economic transition in the former Soviet
Union. Compared to central
European cities like Prague, Warsaw and Budapest, Moscow still retains more vestiges
of the Communist era legacy and the dual-economic (Soviet and post-Soviet)
models coexist, sometimes uneasily, in a city undergoing dramatic changes.
(Between 1992 and 1996, the ratio of Moscovites in
federal and city government jobs dropped from 73% to 42% and stabilized
thereafter. (www.mos.ru/eko/eko-book-6.html). We analyze this transition process and the
strategies of Russian federal and Moscow
city authorities in managing and promoting it.
New international economic functions, as well as
the specific locational requirements of new
businesses for prominent office sites, coupled with a relatively tight supply
dating from before 1991, have made Moscow one of the most expensive cities for office rents. At $700 per square meter per year, Moscow
ranks just behind Paris but is more expensive than Chicago, Stockholm, Berlin,
Madrid, Sydney and Brussels (“Office
rents” Economist, January 20, 2001, 106). Yet, an international ranking
by an international consulting firm, William M. Mercer, of “quality of life”
(using 39 criteria ranging from recreational and transport facilities to crime
and education) ranks Moscow second-lowest of all big cities, just ahead of
Mumbai. Moscow ranks well-behind Cairo,
Bangkok, Rio de Janeiro, Istanbul, and Buenos Aires, and, of course, European
and North American cities (“Quality of life” Economist, March 3, 2001,
98). A profile of high prices for
international businesses and low quality of life for citizens and expatriates
is not untypical of Third
World business
metropolises; cities such as Sao Paolo and Mumbai have experienced it for
decades. Whether Moscow will retain this dual city profile or whether the
new international linkages will result in trickle-down economic benefits to the
great majority of Moscovites is still in
question. In this article, we also
examine the relationship between the new economic functions and the attractions
of the local urban environments since it is increasingly clear that certain
sites in the city are highly-prized while most of the city remains excluded
from the new business developments.
The Informational and World City Concepts
About
the same time as the end of the Cold War and Moscow’s re-integration into the globalizing world
economy, significant debate and research began among Western academics about
world-cities – their conformation, extent, structures, linkages, and global
distribution (Friedmann, 1986; Sassen,
1991). Linked closely with the contemporaneous
proposal of Manuel Castells (1989) on the rise of the
“network society”, the world city literature is characterized by a strong
emphasis on Western, south-east and east Asian
metropolises, the “command and control centers” of the globalizing world economy
(Knox and Taylor, 1995). In order to
examine Moscow’s characterization as a world city by the GaWc
(Globalization and World Cities) group at Loughborough
University (Taylor, 2000), we need to
consider the key elements of the Informational City and world city literatures
to see if these concepts are accurately applied to Moscow a decade after the
end of the Soviet Union.
Castells’ (1989) central argument is that the technology of
the microchip produced advanced, information-based societies, first in key
Western locations and later, through rapid diffusion, in all parts of the
world. By allowing instantaneous
communication between nodes on networks, the “deterritorialized
space of flows” has undermined the space of states (governmental control) and
instituted new realms of capital markets
and financial centers. Control of these new spaces are critical for economic
prosperity in the new information age and conversely, exclusion from the spaces
of flows condemns regions and societies to economic marginalization and
dependency in the globalized world economy. The burgeoning development of tertiary
(service) and quaternary (research and development) spheres of activity in the
leading major world cities has produced restructuring urban functions and serves
as the basis for a growth strategy of municipal and national authorities. In an Informational City, priority is
assigned to the tertiary and quaternary sectors of the economy as the
higher-order functions develop in a dynamic fashion; the city becomes not so
much a place of residence, production and consumption, but one for decision-making, financial
activity, research, and higher education (Castells,
1989, 1996; Claval, 1994; Gottmann
and Harper, 1990; Graham and Domini, 1991; Graham, 1994). In other words, an Informational City becomes a place brimming with information and intense personal
business contacts, and a control center of the management of new information in
a globalized society and economy. Therefore, crucial changes in the cities aspiring
to attain such status and get integrated into the world-wide network of
megalopolises are associated with the rapid development of the financial credit
sphere and management, representation activity, business services and
information technologies (O’Loughlin, 1992).
Four key features of an Informational City have been identified. It is a
place that a) accommodates international, national, regional government, and
non-government organizations, authorized to make far-reaching political,
diplomatic, legal, economic, military and other decisions; b) that contains a
broad range of potential direct contacts among highly-differentiated
organizations, including adequate infrastructure and transport for such
contacts; c) that provides a high level of communication (accessibility), both
transport and informational, with other decision-making or global cities; and
d) that has organizational structures and institutes to amass and process
information essential for business development, political activity, etc., as well
as making available an appropriate choice of business facilities and a
producer-service sector (financial, consulting, banking, real estate,
accounting, advertising services). The Informational City concept emerged at the junction of views on world cities and the new
informational society. Castells (1993) noted that the Informational City is the urban expression of the whole matrix of determinations of the
informational society, just as the industrial city was the spatial expression
of the nineteenth-century industrial society.
The processes constituting this new urban phenomenon are understood by
referring to contemporary social and economic trends that are restructuring
national territories.
The
coming of the Informational City and the discussion of a post-modern stage of
societal development have revealed two approaches that serve as the basis for
the urban planning and management strategy.
Logan and Molotch (1987) developed the concept
of the “city as a growth machine": the territory of a city is used by political forces that
control it to increase combined rent permanently, turning a place or territory
into a commodity that is then “sold” on the real estate market. This
approach is backed by state support of private investments but the adverse
social effects of the resulting growth are rarely compensated by state and city
governments. The typical outcomes of
these processes are social polarization of the population, residential
functions forced out of the center of the city, and a break-up of the city
space into isolated, well-protected expanses owned by individuals or companies.
Harvey’s (1989a, 1989b) "entrepreneurial city"
concept offers a complimentary model of the post-modernist development of
megalopolises. Harvey regarded the historical destinies of major cities
in a broader, global context in which there is stiff competition among the
cities as they vie for new investors. To
withstand such challenges and keep the status acquired earlier, cities launch
ambitious and expensive programs of remodeling city centers in order to
re-create their favorable image. At the
same time, states and municipalities are increasingly unable and reluctant to
cover social expenses involved in improving city centers. To facilitate these changes, the paradigm of
the city management system is altered and transits from “traditional” to a so-called “entrepreneurial”
management. The new entrepreneurial
strategy of city management usually involves 1) public-private partnerships; 2)
a market-oriented nature for the entire activity; 3)
assumption by the municipalities of part of the risk associated with private
investments; and 4) participation of the local state in partnership with real
estate interests.
In a bid to enhance their
competitiveness, including the rivalry with nearby and distant suburbs,
administrations of central cities set up business improvement districts, of
which there were over 1000 in the USA by the early 1990s (Mallett,
1994). These districts are special
property tax zones that have been legally implemented for use in promoting
special services not available to other districts of the city. These services include improvements in
transportation access, creation of an attractive urban environment, and ensuring
tidiness and security. A private
non-commercial company, headed by managers elected from among the real estate
owners, usually runs a business improvement district. For countries such as Russia or the new industrializing economies of South-East Asia, North American and European experience is
crucial when choosing rational, up-to-date city management strategies that, at
the same time, take account of context- specific international economic
features.
World-cities were first described by Peter Hall
(1983) in the 1960s and by the mid-1980s, he could identify eight such places
as metropolises of economic and political power; Moscow
has always been on the list. It was Friedmann (1986) that formalized the “world city concept”
by proposing a set of interrelated theses on the linkage between urbanization
and economic globalization. These theses
incorporated capital flows, migration flows, social polarization, and political
outcomes were formalized into the world city concept later by Friedmann (1995, 43) as a synthesis “ of what would otherwise
be disparate and diverging researches – into labor markets,
information technology, international migration, cultural studies,
city-building processes, industrial location, social class formation, massive
disempowerment and urban politics”. In Friedmann’s view, a world city should thus be a major
financial center and a focus for the headquarters of international companies
and international organizations. To
service the decision-making functions, business producer-service facilities
must be readily available and the city is likely also to become an important
international transportation center.
Finally, a world city must be a fairly large city with
highly-diversified functions, that certainly should
include manufacturing industry, even though it may cease to play the role of a
locomotive in regional development or to perform an urban-planning
function. By these criteria, for
example, Washington DC
is not a world city but Moscow
seems to meet the criteria. The general
thesis and the roster of world cities, with their hierarchical strata, were
confirmed later by the empirical work of the GaWc
group (Beaverstock, Smith and Taylor, 1999; Fossaert, 2001).
Strict criteria for world city status were
suggested by Sassen (1991, 1993) and Shakhar (1990), pointing out that a center may only qualify
provided its transnational companies and banks/financial services operate on a
global scale. Beaverstock
et al. (2000, 47) stress the linkages between world cities in their
determination of world city status and developments: “world cities are produced
and reproduced by what flows through
them (information, knowledge, money and cultural functions”(italics
in original). However, unfortunately,
relatively little data are available for place-to-place flows, as most statistics
are still state-based. In order to
examine world city functions, the GaWc group collect
data on producer services (offices, banks, law firms, accounting firms,
advertising and media functions, stock and bonds trading, and accountancy, on
migrations of low and high-skilled individuals), and engage in content analysis
of business pages in order to track the economic linkages of the world
cities. In this paper, we replicate some
of these data-gathering exercises in order to check their argument that Moscow is now a world city. Specifically, we gather data on banks,
producer services, airport and telephone
communications.
Until now, the GaWc
group has overlooked many aspects of the world city phenomenon, especially the
internal dynamics (governmental control, increased polarization, office park locational strategies and business area
gentrification). All of these elements
are visible in contemporary Moscow. O’Loughlin and Friedrich (1996) identify
additional features of world cities stressing the dual-city nature of the
phenomenon, following Mollenkopf and Castells (1991), counterposing
the “citadel” of high-rise reflective glass office buildings to the “ghetto” of
run-down housing on the outskirts of the city and in other unattractive
locations. Social polarization is
particularly aggravated in cities with a shrinking industrial base, a trend
that is well underway in Moscow
but has effectively ended in many Western cities as services have replaced the
secondary manufacturing sector as the prime locus of most jobs. So far, comparative studies suggest that
social polarization is relatively lower in European than in U.S. cities (see the studies in O’Loughlin and Friedrichs, 1996 and also, Wacquant,
1993). Moscow still seems to be in the incipient stage of
social polarization as evidenced in Vendina’s paper
in this special issue.
Key Developments in Moscow in
the Past Decade
In
their factor analysis of corporate service complexes of 53 European cities,
Taylor and Hoyler (2000) find that Moscow fits squarely into a sub-set of East European
cities (with Warsaw, Kiev and Bucharest). The
corporate mix shows high levels of banking and accountancy, a feature of
Western capitalist development in the post-Communist societies. In Fossaert’s
(2001) spatial extension of this European analysis for the world system, Moscow is again one of five cities within a “Europe in transition” zone and he concludes that, while Moscow is now integrated into the European (and by
extension) world system of cities, the economic returns to Western firms have
been small, fleeting and unpredictable.
More than many other world cities, Moscow is differentiated from its neighboring regions (Ioffe and Nefedova, 1998). The average income gap between Moscovites and other Russians was (late 2000) about 4 to 1
(and according to calculations of the Moscow city government, as much as 7 to 1). Like many other capitalist countries, new and
old, regional economic disparities in Russia seem to be strengthening under contemporary
globalization (Agnew, 2000).
On the surface level, Moscow can claim to play the role of a world city. It is obvious that the conversion of Moscow into an Informational City is an important first step on the way to the club of world cities,
the command and control centers that shape society at the turn of the
millennium. At least, on the scale of the former Soviet Union, the city is a
major business and international political center, and firms like RAO Gazprom (gas), LUKOil (oil), RAO
EES Rossii (electricity), Rostelekom
(telecommunications) and some banks have
virtually become transnational companies, even though they are less powerful
compared with the leading Western ones. Moscow remains Russia’s major international aviation hub with 73% of
all traffic (down from about 82% in Soviet times). (Aviatsionno-Kosmicheskii
Spravochnik Stran SNG i Baltii, 1998/99). One weakness preventing further economic
growth is the inadequate business service infrastructure that meets
international standards. The improvement
of this infrastructure and promotion to the rank of a world city, holding the long-awaited
promise of substantial political and economic benefits to Russia as a whole,
lies behind the concerted effort of the state, the city and private capital in
an entrepreneurial effort described by Harvey (1989a). Within Moscow, the three largest projects in recent years (the Manezh Squate shopping center
beside Red Square, the building of the Christ the Savior Cathedral
nearby, and the international office quarter, “Moscow City”, 4 kilometers west of the Kremlin along the Moscow river) have all involved
huge public involvement on the part of the Moscow city government.
A free market does not exist as considerable controls and
constraints have been imposed by the municipality on the market economy as a specific Moscow vision of the public-private relationship has
evolved under the aegis of Mayor Yuri Luzhkov (Gubanov, 1999; Pagonis and Thornley,
2000).
A characteristic feature of Moscow over the last few
decades has been an unusual combination of concentrated political power (though
this dates back to Tsarist times), decision-making functions, control and management and a
high employment rate in science on the one
hand, and a concentration of outdated industry, including metallurgy, weaving industry, and chemical
industries on the other (Lappo, Golz
and Treivish, 1988; Lappo,
1992). Available statistical data show
hyper-concentration of commercial and go-between functions in the capital. (For
comparison, Moscow has 5.8% of Russia’s
population). In 1999-2000, Moscow
companies accounted for more than 38% of all currency incomes from export of
goods and services, while the city’s production comprised only a small part of
the Russian total (5%). Moscow
banks account for 65-80% of all foreign currency operations. Moscow accumulated 27.8% of foreign
investments in the country between 1991-1998 and in 1998, 56% of joint ventures
registered in Russia were based in Moscow, with foreign partnerships
contributing more than 80% of them. (All
statistics from the City of Moscow
website: www.mos.ru). Overall of 89 Russian
regions, Moscow city received 16.7%
of all investment in Russia
with another 5% going to the Moscow
region (the oblast surrounding the city) in 1998. In contrast, St.
Petersburg received only 3% (Investitsionnye no. 39, 1999).
Further evidence of Moscow’s
primacy is readily available. The city
accounts for 13.8% of Russian Gross Domestic Product and 28.7% of retail
turnover. In 2001, industrial output in Russia
was up 4.9% after an increase in 2000 of 9% helped by high world oil prices
(“Industrial output up 4.9%.” Moscow Times, January 21, 2002, 7). In the same year, more than 3000
representatives of foreign companies were officially registered in Moscow.
The capital is by far the main donor to the federal budget and provides it with
32.7% of its tax revenue; moreover, Moscow’s
contribution has considerably grown since 1993, when it reached 11%, explained
by the location of major national companies’ headquarters in the city. Per capita gross regional product of Moscow
is the largest among Russian regions (behind Tiumen
oblast where oil production is dominant) and more than twice the national
average (Ponomarenko, 2000). Per capita income in Moscow
in 2000 was still almost four times as much as the national average,
up from 1995-1996 when it was 3:1.
However, the situation is
gradually changing, especially since the 1998 crisis, which stimulated export
and production of import-replacing goods in the province. Similarly, 1998 marked
a sharp drop in production after national decline in the mid-1990s and only in
2000, was this recovered. The crisis
also provoked a redistribution of foreign investments in favor of the
provinces: in 1996, the ratio of Moscow
in the total investment amount reached 66.0% and in 1997, 67.4%, but in 1998 it
had decreased to 48.9%. In January-June
2000, it dropped further to 32.5%. In
the same period, the ratio of Moscow in direct foreign investments was about
26% - much less than only three years before, though still much higher than the
capital’s ratio in population. There has
been a continued decrease of Moscow’s
contribution of Moscow to federal
budget, although not as pronounced as the drop in the ratio of foreign
investments.
In
the 1990s, the economy of Moscow
survived a period of rapid restructuring.
At the end of the decade, the structure of employment has become much
more similar to major world metropolises than ten years before, as Moscow is progressively losing its importance as an
industrial center. For political
reasons, the Soviet leadership did their best to keep a large working-class
population in the capital. In the 1970s
and 1980s, economists and even the city authorities realized that it was
necessary to withdraw obsolete, polluting and labor-consuming branches of
industry from Moscow and that a certain deindustrialization had become
unavoidable. Hence, this process was
slow but, under unregulated market
conditions after 1991, it sharply accelerated.
By the end of the decade, non-productive functions definitely dominated
(Table 1). At the all-Russian scale, the
specialization of Moscow (measured as ratio of employed in the given
branch to the ratio of this activity in Russia as a whole) was in research (the capital contains
more than one-third of Russians employed in this sector), banking and insurance
sphere, telecommunications, and construction works. By the end of the decade, the re-structuring
of employment was dramatic and the cost of such rapid transformations was high,
including the crisis in the most modern, high-tech branches of industry and
declining scientific activity.
Table 1: Ratio of employed in Manufacturing and Non-Productive Sphere
(% of total employment)
Principal
Spheres of Employment
|
1990
|
1993
|
1999
|
Productive sphere
|
54.3
|
49.8
|
29.0
|
of which
Industry
|
23.8
|
21.9
|
14.3
|
Non-productive sphere
|
45.7
|
50.2
|
71.0
|
of which
Trade
|
9.8
|
12.7
|
18.0
|
of which
Finance and Real Estate
|
0.5
|
1.3
|
2.7
|
Sources: Balans trudovykh resursov, 1991; Balans trudovykh resursov, 1994, Adminstrativnye okruga…, 1999.
Compared with other major
cities, the analysis of structural shifts that occurred in Moscow
between 1991 and 2000 indicates that, despite the general trends, the Russian
capital lags at least 15-20 years behind the largest world cities. In terms of
the development of the sphere of business facilities, especially, Moscow
is a particular laggard (Gritsai, 1996, 1997). At the same time, as the key node of Russia's
international relations, Moscow
increasingly looks to the major cities of the West. For example, over the last decade, the number
of air flights linking Moscow directly with cities in the U.S. has more than
quadrupled and has reached about 40 connections a week, while with Western
European cities, flights have increased by more than one and a half times
(about 430 connections a week) (Table 2).
By 1996, for the first time in Russian civil aviation history, the
number of passengers at the Moscow
international hub (as well as St. Petersburg’s
hub) exceeded domestic passenger numbers.
In total, almost 8 million passengers left Moscow
for foreign destinations in 1996.
Comparing 1997 to 1985, the numbers give a clear indication of the
reorientation of Russia. In 1985, 86% of flights from Russia
were to other CIS (former Soviet republics) and by 1997,
this ratio was down to 34%. In contrast,
the ratio of flights to East-Central Europe rose from 7% to 9% with the biggest
increases coming in the flights to Western Europe (up from 4% to 28%) and Asia
(up from 1.5% to 26%). Ratios for the
other world regions (less than 1%) were unchanged.
In the summer 2000
timetable, 978 flight connections per week (arrivals and departures) linked Moscow’s
Sheremetyevo airport with destinations in Western
Europe (Table 2). Frankfurt,
London and Paris
(with 124 connections each), Berlin
(105) and Stockholm (88) were the
top traffic nodes. By contrast, despite
the geographic propinquity and historical ties, only about one-third that number linked Moscow
to Eastern European cities. Other world
regions, with the exception of the Middle East including
Israel,
maintained few connections. Though the
traffic was lighter in the winter season, these regional ratios are maintained.1 Since international traffic is
growing rapidly year-to year (up 6.8% in 2001 – “Sheremetyevo
traffic” Moscow Times, January 21, 2002, 8), a much-needed expansion and modernization of the 1980-era airport
is planned.
Table 2: Total Connections from Moscow’s Sheremetyevo Airport.
Destinations
|
Summer 2000
|
Winter 01-02
|
Western Europe
|
978
|
664
|
East-Central Europe
|
342
|
269
|
Commonwealth of Independent States
|
172
|
222
|
Latin America
|
22
|
4
|
East and South-east Asia
|
97
|
94
|
South Asia
|
47
|
30
|
Africa
|
10
|
2
|
Middle East-North Africa
|
54
|
70
|
North America
|
66
|
62
|
Total Foreign Destinations
|
1788
|
1417
|
|
Source: Sheremetyevo Airport flight guides, Summer 2000 and Winter
2001-02
Another commonly used indicator of international
linkages is telephone traffic. Though it
is possible to agree with the reservations of Beaverstock
et al. (2000) about the difficulty of
separating business from personal traffic in both telephone and air traffic,
the data clearly indicate the variable strength of Moscow’s external relationships. In 1998, telephone
traffic with the “far abroad” (beyond the borders of the former Soviet Union) reached half of total foreign traffic. As in air travel, Germany provides the focus of the traffic with the “far
abroad”, maintaining its position from 1994 with over 10% of all calls. (Table
3) Other western countries with strong
business and personal (through emigration) links with Moscow also predominate in the links (US, France, Italy and the UK). Little
evidence remains of the strong economic and political links of Soviet times; of
the former Communist states, only Yugoslavia, Vietnam, the Czech Republic, Poland, Bulgaria and Hungary have more than 1% of contemporary Moscow telephone calls.
The Russian capital finds itself increasingly incorporated into the
complicated system of interaction between the leading links of the world system
of cities (Kolossov and Vendina, 1997, Kolossov, 2000).
Table 3: Moscow
international phone traffic, 1994 and 1998 (% of total traffic with “Far
Abroad”)
|
More than 10%
|
10%-5%
|
5%-3%
|
3-1%
|
1%-0.5%
|
1994
|
Germany, USA
|
UK, Italy,
France
|
Finland, Austria, Switzerland, Poland
|
Turkey, Israel, Netherlands, Yugoslavia, India, Hungary, Belgium,
Spain, Bulgaria, China, Sweden, Greece, Cyprus,
Czech Republic, UAE,
Denmark.
|
Japan, Croatia, Singapore Slovakia, Norway
|
1998
|
Germany
|
USA, UK,
Italy
|
France, Yugoslavia, Vietnam, Turkey
|
China, Israel,
Czech Republic, Poland, Switzerland, Finland, India, Netherlands, Austria,
Hungary, Bulgaria, Cyprus, Greece, Belgium, Sweden
|
Pakistan, United Arab Emirates, Syria, Denmark, Japan, Slovakia, Korea, Croatia, Iran
|
The position of Moscow is dominant in virtually all indicators of the
financial-and-banking system. In 1999, its ratio in the financial employment
sector reached 19.1%. Of the top 50
banks in Russia in 2000 (capital measured in rubles), 18 of the
top 20 are based in Moscow (one based in Kazan held 7th position and the 20th
rank was held by a St. Petersburg bank). Altogether, 40 of the top 50 banks are
from Moscow, a clear indication of its primacy in banking
activity (300 krupeishikh,
1999, 36-48). Huge amounts are
accumulated in Moscow banks: by 1995, Moscow's ratio of Russia's total bank assets amounted to 83.2%. Even the 1998 financial crisis did not shake
the monopoly of Moscow banks. In
1999, the ratio of Moscow banks in total capital of first 50 banks remained
at 79.8%, not including the oldest and by far the largest bank of Russia – the state Sberbank
(Savings Bank), which controls the bulk of banking operations with
individuals. The Moscow ratio reaches 87.6% if Sberbank
is included.
In recent years, Moscow
has regained the traffic it had before the August 1998 financial crash and the
international activity of Moscow
banks has increased considerably. Now, Moscow
is attaining the status of an international financial center, at least in the
CIS financial markets. A number of Moscow
banks stand a good chance of becoming transnational. Across the Russian
Federation, Vneshtorgbank has a tradition extensive
network and recently opened branches in Hungary, India, Italy, Cyprus, China,
the US, Turkey, Czech Republic and Switzerland. Moscow Savings Bank has opened
an office in the Netherlands. Since 1991, many Moscow
banks have managed to establish correspondent relations with the leading banks
of the western countries and have become members of international settlement
and information systems (SWIFT, REUTERS, etc.).
Foreign banks are not active in advancing into Moscow's
financial markets since decisions taken by the
Russian government restrict the operations of foreign banks in Russia
for the period of transition. The
Central Bank of Russia
confined the proportion of foreign banks in the amount of the country's banking
capital to 12%. Most leading foreign
banks have offices in Moscow, along
with the offices of international financial institutions (World Bank, European
Bank of Reconstruction and Development, etc.), but no bank is admitted to
normal banking operations with Moscovites.
During the immediate
post-Perestroika period (1992-1996), Moscow
acted as a go-between for Russia's
regions and advanced countries of the West.
The lion's share of purchase-and-sale deals for primaries and other
materials were concluded in Moscow.
Various consumer items were channeled to Moscow:
its ratio in the officially registered retail turnover is many times its ratio
of the country's population and between 1992 and 1999,
it rose from 16% to 29.6% of the Russian total.
In 1999, the capital’s ratio in the turnover of personal services
reached 28% and Moscow accounts for
41% of all purchases of foreign exchanges by individuals. Thus, within a short
time, Moscow managed to take
advantage of its favorable objective prerequisites and benefits stemming from
the position of a centralized primate city to establish, in the new capitalist
conditions, control over the huge financial and commodity flows. Supporting the conclusions in Taylor and Hoyler (1999), Moscow’s role as an economic node between
the West and Russia was not only noticeable locally but also in other capitals of
Russia’s neighboring countries, among them, Tallinn (Estonia), Riga (Latvia),
Helsinki (Finland), Warsaw (Poland), and Kiev (Ukraine). Of course, such a hypertrophy of Moscow’s
functions as an intermediary between Russia
and the international market, as well as its
absolute dominance at the national financial market
will weaken as the economic situation in the country becomes normalized. Moreover, Russia’s
economy can be stable only if it is develops a balanced network of regional
metropolises. It is likely that the capital will certainly keep its unique
position for a long time (Nefedova and Treivish, 1994). By 2000, there were no visble
signs of waning dominance.
Moscow
Planning in a Time of Economic and Political Change
The master plan of Moscow's
development to 2020, adopted in 2000, tying together the social, economic and
functional problems of development, has now been succeeded by programs
envisaging priority development and renovation of its component parts. The entrepreneurial approach as described by Harvey
(1989a), reflecting the rejection of a traditional city management strategy,
has triumphed in the Russian capital.
But does it mean that the entrepreneurial concept (focused on the engagement of public
capital in private real estate speculation) has been embraced? It is hard to give an unambiguous answer to
this question. In a bid to avoid, or at
least to minimize, undesirable competition, Moscow
is trying hard to integrate into the world economy, specifically as an Informational
City that has all the necessary
managerial, financial, information and service infrastructure. In so doing, the Moscow
city government, following the initiative of Mayor Yuri Luzhkov,
is taking an active part in this process, seeking to establish purposefully
up-to-date business districts in specific locations (Pagonis and Thornley, 2000).
Nearly all current ambitious projects are associated with this
public-private partnership strategy including the proposed construction of the
high-speed railroad from the center of Moscow to Sheremetyevo
airport; the business airport at Tushino; the
high-speed railroad from Moscow to St. Petersburg; a crash program of building
a commercial and cultural center in Manezhnaya Ploshchad (Manezh Square)
completed in 1997, implementation of the Moscow City Projects – a new zone of
100 story sky-scrapers, remodeling the center-city districts of Arbat and Sretenka, and
restructuring of the Kremlin island. The
ambitious Third Motorway Ring project was mostly completed by late 2001, except
for some eastern sections including a 3 kilometer tunnel under the historical
blocks of Lefortovo.
Networks of supermarkets
and department stores, recently built in cooperation with the largest European
companies, are a recent development. Sixteen big department stores of the Perekrestok (Cross-Road) network, 5 Ramstores, two
stores of IKEA (a Swedish furniture chain), are open or under
construction. These and other retail
initiatives have caused a retail boom. Moscow
has just 300,000 square meters of “civilized retail space” (supermarkets,
hypermarkets, and shopping centers) but nearly
double that amount will be constructed in 2001-02 alone. This spurt is partly generated by a growing
retail splurge by Russians (about 10% last year; incomes are rising about 9%
per year) and mostly by a renewed interest by Western companies in Russia. (Between 1998 and 1999, the
average Moscovite’s income plummeted from $8000 to
$2800 but it has now recovered to $5970). Since Moscow
has only 35 square meters of “civilized retail space” per resident (compared to
174 square meters in Prague, 217 in
Warsaw, 275 in London
and 398 in Paris, according to
Jones, Lang, LaSalle Consultants), there is a lot of opportunity for
growth. Furthermore, Moscovites
spend 80% of their income on retail consumer goods (London
is 38% and Prague is 40%), with
two-thirds of this expenditure still going to kiosks and outdoor markets. Mayor Luzhkov is
committed to converting the kiosks and outdoor markets
to indoor shopping spaces ordering 106 of the city’s 200 outdoor markets
closed by the end of 2002. (All figures
from Startseva, 2001).
The
contemporary Moscow urban planning practice is clearly aimed at
taking advantage of the benefits of linking Moscow, as the key economic center in Russia, to the world economy. The Moscow city government is seeking access to resources
from the private sector but at the same time, the Luzhkov
authorities want to establish their control over the most profitable spheres of
the urban economy. This long-standing
urban planning tradition emanating from Soviet times does not allow market processes to develop spontaneously and freely
since tradition imposes substantial regulations, often used to ensure
participation of the city in economic projects or at least, in the distribution
of their results. Whether such a policy
is justified by the need to combine the private interests of investors with
collective interests of city residents remains an open question. Proposed projects are evaluated in terms of
“value for the city”, direct participation of the local state in implementing
many projects, and development of programs and proposals promotes the capital's
business sphere by urban planning institutions (Moskva, 2001). Moreover, the traditions and accumulated
experience of urban planning solutions of the Communist period impede the
progress of the entrepreneurial mentality.
There is a temptation to transform old ideas and projects to accord with
the new capitalist realities, with unexpected results.
A
characteristic example of the new thinking is “Project Proposals for the
Development of a
System of City Centers” (Proektnye
predlozhenia po razvitiu sistemy
gorodskikh tsentrov)
submitted by the Moscow Master Plan Institute to the Moscow Government in May,
1996, as a concept of territorial development for business improvement
districts in Moscow. In this document, one can see the imprint of
the old master plans and lack of a clear idea of what a business district
is. The historic core of the city is
regarded in an undifferentiated manner; it is assumed that all of it will be
converted into a business district. The
former centers of town (dozens of planning districts) are ”assigned”
the roles of intra-urban business centers.
Over the past few years, they have become the focal points of
spontaneous trade development, with street markets
and kiosks near Metro stations regarded as local business centers. The draft document almost totally fails to
portray any knowledge of the contemporary peculiarities of the location and
real estate market in the city. The inefficiency and woeful performance of
state planning institutions has given rise to a situation where their functions
have been assumed by architectural-planning or real estate companies in
coordinating diverse areas of activity, from project inception to final
implementation. These firms can
demonstrate to the Moscow Government how expeditious their urban planning
solutions are and, at the same time, meet growing consumer demand.
Even with state or municipal participation,
private companies do not pursue altruistic social goals, but give preference to
corporate interests. This is particularly evident in the center of Moscow where ”elite”
office-cum-residence complexes are under construction. These developments
comprise a group of buildings with a complete range of residential and business
functions and a well-developed infrastructure in the form of garages, swimming
pools, gyms, security, playgrounds, etc.
The urban environment of the center is being fragmented. Some blocks like a series of housing-office
complexes in Sretenka (northern part of the center
city) are turning into a "packaged product", being oriented to a
particular kind of activity for a specific group of visitors-residents, who are
growing increasingly isolated in self-contained communities. Ordinary Moscovites find themselves total strangers in these
developments and, typically, they are not admitted. The socio-political climate in the capital is
thus quickly turning the urban environment into a source of land use
conflicts.
Although the use of a marketing approach to city development started about 5
years ago, its strong and weak points are already obvious. The strong points include mobilization of
various financial sources and the creative potential of urban planners for
genuine reconstruction and enhancement of city services and utilities on a
scale comparable only to the Stalinist era (1922-53). The obvious weakness is that projects are
isolated, corporate, extremely costly, and ignorant of the social
situation. Furthermore, the citizens of Moscow have no say in the decisions that are made. Attempts to solve these problems using
relatively traditional methods of planning consist of pursuing a "city for
residence" policy (locating homes side by side with the offices),
entertainment facilities, prestigious residential houses, trade zones, cultural
and leisure centers intended primarily for the "day-time" population
of the city. Such a policy is designed
to safeguard the city center from "privatization", to try to
reconstruct a functionally interrelated urban environment by linking areas
closed to the public with attractive community spaces. However, despite these
plans, the “dual city” phenomenon (Mollenkopf and Castells, 1991) is quickly being constituted in Moscow. (See also Vendina’s
article in this issue).
The Formation of Business
Districts in Moscow
The
propensity to establish areas within Moscow where offices of various producer service firms,
shops, credit-and-finance institutions, and state organizations are
concentrated, calls for a detailed street-by-street analysis of their
distribution. Unlike most of the world
city literature, we are extending the consideration of changes to the
intra-urban character of the city. Our
sources of information are the many and voluminous reference/informational and
advertising publications (Moscow Yellow Pages, Tsentr-Plus,
Extra-M, etc). In the analysis of
intra-Moscow developments, we used post office codes as our territorial units
thus making it possible to link institutions in different spheres of activity
with the postal zones. Nearly 500
post-office districts service the residential areas of the city. Where firms or
organizations functioned as part of major institutions (ministries, institutes,
enterprises, etc.) and used a departmental post-code, these were assigned a
different address according to the specific street location. In total, we have more than 14,000 locations. The data are for 1996 and 2000, and are
analyzed according to the retail trade, banking/financial services, and
business services categories.
Retail Trade: Trade, an
indicator of the eternal linkages of cities, can hardly be regarded as an
“innovative” type of activity. For
post-Soviet Moscow, however, trade has performed an innovation role,
having assumed the function of the primary motivating force, not only of
entrepreneurial activity, but also of urban development. Trade in general, and shop windows in
particular, generate a certain street atmosphere constituting one of the
crucial factors that form the image of a place.
The correlation between the prestige of a place and the concentration of
the new tertiary and quaternary economy is obvious. By and large, the spatial picture of the
distribution of shops, exceeding 7,000 in 1996 (not counting the numerous
kiosks found in all neighborhoods but clustered near the Metro stations) is
characterized by dominance of the center, where the number of street traders
and trading firms is many times greater than the outskirts. Mayor Luzhkov is
successfully trying to upgrade the kiosks, getting rid of them as urban blight
and progressively replacing them with pavilions and shopping malls. In 2000,
there were already about 24,000 shops, and 10,600 kiosks in Moscow and the 223 surviving
street markets mainly served people with limited incomes.
![](Infocity_image002.jpg)
Figure 1
- The density of stores selling non-alimentary products in 2000. Source:
All Moscow, 2000; advertising newspapers, 2000.
However, the center of Moscow is far from uniform.
Within it, one can distinguish the most prestigious and the most peripheral
districts, transition districts and districts of varying specialization. For example, the pattern of the network of shops
and firms dealing in books and stationery goods conforms to the shape of the
Boulevard and Sadovoye Rings; furniture stores
gravitate towards the north-eastern sector of Moscow's historical core. (See Figure 1). Of
special interest is the distribution of shops dealing in luxury items, art,
antiques, and high-priced boutiques. These are true indicators of prestige and
attraction of a particular place. Judging by the distribution of prestigious
shops, the quarters adjoining the Kremlin are most attractive, sited within the
Boulevard Ring, Tverskaya ulitsa,
Arbat and Novy Arbat with the
neighboring sections of the nearby House of Government, the Balchug area
(Kremlin Island), Sadovoye Ring around Bronnaya Streets, Kutuzovsky
Prospect near the Triumphal Arch and Park Pobedy, the
districts of Zamoskvorechye, Frunzenskaya
Embankment, Taganka ploshchad, the All-Russian Exhibition Center (VVTs) and the areas around
the Universitet and Profsoyuznaya
Metro stations. The contrast between
these prestigious loci and peripheral territories is striking. Nevertheless, two outer areas are worthy of
note. Here the locational
prestige is high at present and likely to increase over time - the area near
the Airport Metro station and a rather large territory between the Akademicheskaya and Kaluzhskaya
Metro stations, along Profsoyuznaya Street..
The economic crisis of August
1998 seriously undermined the development of tertiary activities. In September
1998, at least 200,000 people employed in the new privatized sectors of the
economy lost their jobs, and salaries of others measured in US dollars usually
diminished to about one third of the pre-crisis level. Some Western companies
ceased their activity in Russia, most
often in Moscow. Most preferred to wait for better times, and
in Moscow, they came
soon; the capital recovered much faster than in other Russian regions. At the same time, inflation slowed down, the
industrial production and the turnover of retail trade and services started to
grow again by 1999, and positive tendencies significantly strengthened in 2000,
in economic terms, the most successful year for post-Soviet Russia. The Moscow economy as
a whole suffered from economic losses only in 1998, losing 34.6 billion
rubles. Already in 1999, the result was
positive (+72.5 billion rubles). As a result, ambitious projects were not
stopped. However, incomes have not yet
reached the 1997 level, especially salaries of those who are paid from the
state budget; in January-May 2000, they had only reached 86% of the 1997
level. Since a large proportion of
consumers could not afford expensive imported goods, it stimulated domestic
production. In the real estate market, prices
diminished, too, especially for cheap housing.
Finance. The specificity of requirements demanded for
a particular location by the finance-and-credit sphere may be determined by
analysis of the banking system, its most crucial and
sprawling industry. In terms of the
number of commercial banks per capita of the population, Moscow is far ahead of
the provinces, with one commercial bank in the capital for every 8,900
Muscovites, six and half times the Russian average. Muscovites are now provided with banks and
banking institutions at the level comparable to many Western countries. In West Germany, for example, in 1990,
there was one banking institution per 9000 people. However, as far as the diversity and quality
of facilities offered, Moscow banks still lag behind
those in the West. Moscow banks typically offer
about 80 kinds of services, compared to about 200 in Western banks. One of the most serious consequences of the
1998 crisis was the crash of seven of the largest Moscow banks.
Moscow's historic core is
clearly visible as the zone of concentration and highest activity in the
banking sphere (Figure 2). While seeking
to gain a place in the center of the city, the banks compete successfully with
other, less prosperous and powerful spheres of activity, forcing them out of
their long-standing locations. Trading and retail firms are sometimes unable to
compete for space with the banks. There
is little doubt that it was the remodeling of old premises for bank offices
that marked the beginning of the widespread architectural
transformation of Moscow's core that we witness
today. Moscow’s pre-Revolutionary
heritage has had a notable effect upon the accommodation of banks. Nearly all former bank buildings revived
their functions, often after 70 years of Communist control. As a rule, these buildings house the
headquarters of major commercial banks, set up with the participation of the
federal state capital. Moreover, they
have been centers of attraction for the establishment of new banks nearby. For example, at Kuznetsky
Most, in addition to the Head Office of the Bank of Russia, the country's major
banks, such as Vneshtorgbank of Russia, are also
located.
![](Infocity_image004.jpg)
Figure 2 - Main offices and branches of Russian and foreign banks in 1996 (not
including Sberbank).
Sources: All Moscow, 2000; advertising newspapers, 2000.
The location of “sectoral” banks, established on the basis of their
connections to state ministries and departments, almost invariably corresponds
to the location of their founders. The
same goes for the location of some banks of large enterprises and organizations. Usually, such banks are housed in the
buildings owned by their sponsors, and as a result, are scattered over the
city. From mid-1994, Moscow has been an arena of
stiff competition among the numerous commercial banking institutions whose
strategy is to attract clients from different parts of the city and to cover
its entire area with a network of their branches. However, more often than not,
such facilities are aimed either at legal entities or high-income
individuals. It is not by mere chance,
therefore, that banks seek to open their divisions and branches in the busiest
and most prestigious avenues of the city - Tverskaya ulitsa, Novi Arbat, Sadovoye
Ring, Leninsky Prospekt,
and Prospect Mira. The network of branches proves to be very closely associated
with the head offices of the banks; the correlation coefficient is +0.67.
The unusually high
concentration of bank offices is indicative of the high prestige of particular Moscow districts, coinciding
with the districts where expensive stores are concentrated. Along with the Boulevard Ring, Arbat, Balchug, Taganka, Petrovka and Neglinka are becoming increasingly important as they form
one cluster together with Tverskaya. Apart from these, new banking districts are Pokrovka Street and Pokrovsky Boulevard, the area near the Oktyabrskaya metro station, and the adjoining Yakimanka and Sadovoye Ring are
also evident. Outside the center of
Moscow, as well as on the outskirts of the city, there also emerge notable
points of banking activity growth. These
include Prospect Mira-Ostankino, the area around the Tulskaya Metro station, and Kutuzovsky
Prospect - especially its section around the Triumphal Arch. Additionally, a
rather sprawling district, though mixed in land-use, in the south-west of the
city, including Leninsky Prospect and Profsoyuznaya Street from Gagarin Square to the Yugo-Zapadnaya and Kaluzhskaya
Metro stations, is developing as a banking center. As yet, none of these outlying districts can
match the center in terms of attraction or the level of bank concentrations.
Producer
and Business Services - Referred to as “activity to promote market development" in
the official statistics, these firms include activities that have emerged in
Russia only after 1991: real estate operations, advertising, audit,
accountancy, economic and political consulting, mediation firms of all
description (brokers, dealers), computer and telecommunication facilities,
consultants, business tourism and firms organizing business meetings and
conferences. The list includes more
traditional, but definitely modernized spheres, such as transportation and
postal facilities, as well as education.
The producer service
sector has grown in different ways but, above all, it exists in Moscow as a
kind of applied activity of institutions and firms that accumulate capital,
especially major banks, investment and construction companies. Many of the firms dealing in business service
were initially set up jointly with state bodies since relations with the
“parent” organization at the outset assisted a new company to promote business
technically as well as administratively, such as in leasing an office at an
acceptable price. Therefore, most firms
of this nature are accommodated in the buildings of the “parent” organizations. For example, a major real estate firm is
located in the building of the Central Real Estate Exchange (Tsentralnoye buro obmena);
numerous TV advertising agencies are located at the Ostankino
TV Center; advertising and information firms are headquartered in major
publishing houses; the four firms controlling telecommunication and computer
networks (Sovam-Teleport, Rospak,
Iasnet, Tekos) are
housed at the Russian Academy of
Sciences’ Institute of Automated Systems; and Telecom has superseded the
USSR Ministry of Communication Means Industry.
When firms started
“from scratch”, with little initial capital, they were content to have modest
offices. Their main suppliers were
various “lower-quality” ministries, hotels or even guest-houses, research
institutes, computer centers or educational establishments conveniently located
in the city, with an infrastructure dating back to Soviet times but offering
lower leasing rates. The spatial picture
of business service location thus reveals distinct territorial preferences (see
Figure 3). In addition to the center,
these are located in the south-western sector of the capital, which, like the
tail of a comet, stretches from the compact business core, similar to it in
terms of the density and variety of the facilities offered. There are two reasons for such a magnetic
attraction to the south-west: first, a high concentration there of
scientific-research institutes dates from Soviet times and, second, the social
pattern of the population dominated by individuals with a higher education,
engaged in intellectual-scientific activities (Vendina, 1996). Politically, its
distinctive higher socio-economic character can be easily identified in
rayon-based maps. (Kolossov,
1997: see also the maps of Moscow in Vendina’s
article in this special issue).
In the December 1999 elections to the State Duma,
in central and south-western districts, Luzhkov’s
bloc “Fatherland – All Russia” won with about 40% of votes, as in Moscow as a
whole, but center and right parties – Yabloko
and The
Union of Right Forces - received their highest support in this region and
together received more than one-quarter of the ballots. At the same time in these districts, the
failure of President Putin’s Unity in
Moscow was especially evident: only 5-6% of electors
opted for it – less than a quarter of Putin’s support in Russia as a whole.
In other parts of the
periphery of Moscow are districts of high
business service activity, contrasting sharply to the surrounding areas of
deprivation. Such high-profile districts
include Ostankino - VDNKh (now
VVTs), Dynamo- Aeroport and
Voikovskaya, Sokol - Oktyabrskoe Pole,
Boris Filevskaya Street – Krylatskoe,
Krasnopresnenskaya
Embankment - "Ulitsa 1905 goda" Metro station, Sokolniki-Preobrazhenskaya,
Semenovskaya-Izmailovskaya, Pervomaiskaya,
and Dmitrovskoe Shosse near
the 'Molodezhnaya" Hotel.
Interest in the central
part of the city as a locational magnet is not
waning, despite the fact that Moscow’s transport and
communication lines are extremely overloaded, with enormous traffic jams and Metro crowding in the center. However recently, there have been some
attempts to build large office blocks for major companies like Gazprom (natural
gas monopoly) and Sberbank
(Savings Bank) outside the city center. As a complementary kind of activity, business services
will almost certainly follow the leaders, further promoting and saturating the
entrepreneurial environment, creating a special business atmosphere in specific
locations near the edge of the city, a development analogous to the edge city
office parks found in Western Europe and North America (O’Loughlin, 1992). Demand for office space far outstrips supply,
with the vacancy rate dropping to 5% at the end of 2001. Class A office space rents for about $550 per
square meter per annum and class B office space for $400-$480 per square meter
(Ognev, 2001).
The Geography of Business
Districts in Moscow
The business district is a compact segment of the
city, in which the state organizations, head offices of large firms (including
credit and finance institutions) are concentrated, and conditions are provided
for their successful operation in the form of a sprawling system of business
and producer services, telecommunications, and computer communications. The attractive urban environment can be a
kind of a business district visiting card, conveying a symbolic meaning, and
provides various facilities for face-to-face contacts and meeting individual
requirements of the businessmen (restaurants, shops, cultural centers).
One of the crucial conditions of establishing a business district is
good accessibility as well as adquate transport.
The development of a business district is a
time-consuming process. Such districts
began to emerge late in the 19th century when most financial institutions of
Moscow were located in three main districts: (1) Kitai-Gorod,
near the Stock Exchange and Torgovye Ryady (Rows of Stalls); (2)
Kuznetsky Most, side by side with high-priced
and fashionable stores, and (3) around Tverskoy
Boulevard. Many buildings in these
areas, at present largely occupied by state organizations, were built specially
for the banks. For example, in Ilyinka Street (Kitai-Gorod), Moscow’s largest banks were located. Near Kuznetsky Most
were the oldest banking institutions of the capital and Moscow's largest private credit institutions, Junker and
Co. and Dyamgarov Brothers.
Also at this location was Moscow International Commercial Bank (later, United
Bank), a division of "Credit Lyonnais,” the only foreign bank allowed to operate in the
Russian Empire (Klimanov, 1997). Naturally, the formation of a business
district was not restricted to the setting up of a series of banks. It was no coincidence that novelties like Slavyansky Bazar, the
first Russian restaurant in the center (the rest were referred to as "traktir" or eating-houses), was set up in the 1873 in Kitai-Gorod, and the French restaurant, Hermitage, was opened near Kuznetsky Most in the 1840s (it moved in 1864 to the
Boulevard Ring). Not far from the Hermitage, there was Zverev's
Traktir, commonly called “Bread Exchange”; here
millionaire-wholesalers who held the entire bread business in their hands congregated, and all major deals were concluded over a cup
of tea (Gilyarovsky, 1980).
Business districts may be distinguished by the
time of establishment, maturity, and functions they perform, whether they are
multi-functional or specialized, national-international oriented. Established existing districts are understood
as integrated and multi- functional when they feature a great abundance of
business services. Strictly speaking, Moscow business districts cannot be taken as solid since
none of them has clearly defined boundaries, and many even lack a clear self-image. Putative business districts are among the
conveniently located quarters that have crucial prerequisites for the
development of a complete set of business producer functions. They can take the
form of a combination, within a limited area, of large and prestigious hotel
complexes, state bodies, multi-profile trade and office buildings, and
high-quality housing. However, they lag
behind the existing business districts in terms of the abundance of business
services. More importantly, these districts lack sufficient decision-making
loci.
As potential business districts,
locations conveniently sited at the crossing of transport routes outside the
historical part of Moscow are prime targets. These neighborhoods have some prerequisites
for the emergence of crucial business functions already available - advanced
trade, exhibition complexes, individual business centers, headquarters of major
firms, and existing hotels. However,
these areas are not yet compact enough, the available business facilities are
insufficient and the local urban environment remains unattractive. To encourage further development, more
concentration is needed including the presence of one or more decision-making centers, including
state institutions, major banks, headquarters of Russian national companies
or international companies, and a
well-developed sector of complementary types of activity, particularly business
services. Further, a clear spatial structure is required including the presence
of a dominant business core or several centers, without which the business core
"floats in the air"
and exists separately from the surrounding city environment.
In this study, as we delineated the business districts, quantitative
(density) as well as qualitative (structure) characteristics were
considered. It is possible to
distinguish eight well-established multi-functional business districts in Moscow. Of these,
the first four (Kitai-Gorod, Tverskaya,
Kremlin Island and Myasnitskaya) took shape during the
long process of the historical development of the city's center.
![](Infocity_image006.jpg)
Figure 3 - Companies providing business-services). Sources: All Moscow, 2000; advertising newspapers, 2000.
The business districts that began to form in
Soviet times may be regarded as firmly established rather than historical. These are not compact and their buildings are
grandiose, but the key structures stand far apart from one another, creating
accessibility problems due to inadequate city transport. In many parts of these business districts,
the urban environment is not geared to the individual nor is it developed or
attractive enough. These four Soviet districts are located in Arbatskaya -Novi Arbat, Oktyabrskaya, Ostankinskaya, and Krasnopresnenskaya.
The districts of the historic center of the city that are located
between the dynamically-growing business districts are acquiring a special locational advantage and it is here that prestigious
housing has started to concentrate. The
urban environment in such quarters is being rapidly transformed, bringing in
business services and offices of small firms. These are, above all, Zamoskvorechye and the Sretenka
area of the north central city. (For gentrification
developments in Sretenka, see O’Loughlin, Kolossov
and Vendina, 1997). Scattered
throughout the Moscow landscape in which business facilities abound,
there are numerous gaps so far impenetrable to business activity. These are the areas where crucial centers of
the military command and of the government are located, including the General
Staff, Ministry of Defense, and major government ministries. Bastions of the command and administrative
system in the Soviet past, the districts they command are still excluded from
the city's vital space, remaining as stern and unconquerable as ever.
In addition to the eight existing business
districts identified above, there are five others taking shape in Moscow, with another seven potential zones in the
future. The five developing districts
include Dinamo, Taganskaya Ploshchad, Gagarina Square-Leninsky Prospect, Yugo-Zapadnaya,
including the Olympic Village, and Kutuzovsky
Prospect near the Triumphal Arch and Park Pobedy. The latter may, in the long term, merge with
the existing Arbatskaya district. The seven potential business districts (Izmailovskaya, Filevskaya, Kaluzhskaya, Frunzenskaya, Sokolniki, Universitet and Oktyabrskoe Pole metro) face a serious impediment to their
development in the unsuitability of buildings set up mostly between the 1960s
and 1980s for accommodating banks, small offices or shops. These offices have very little potential for
new construction and have limited “image resources” due to the deterioration of
the mass produced residential houses, of
which there are quite a few in these areas.
Conclusion
Moscow is becoming increasingly like other world cities,
especially in the factors governing locational
choices for business services that are part of the international network of
economic activity. Changing paradigms in
the systems of city management, a transition from plan (government)-based
methods of management
to entrepreneurial methods, the absence of a universal vision of city
redevelopment and of clearly-formulated
entrepreneurial strategies of the local state have all resulted in
positive and negative consequences in Moscow. Russia's capital is faced with virtually the same
phenomena that are observed in all major Western cities that have entered the
era of an informational society.
The adverse world city consequence for Moscow lies in the rapid and basically unplanned growth of superstructure
functions -management, high-order
facilities, trade in exclusive items, and elite housing. In contrast, basic functions (production,
housing, and transport) are quickly declining. The current reconstruction in
the capital involves a limited number of urban districts, while most
neighborhoods lie neglected. Above all, the historic center of Moscow has captured nearly 40% of capital investments
and construction, although it accounts for only 6.4% of the total city area and
its population does not exceed 8%. We
can expect further depopulation of the center, if the experience of central
city neighborhoods is typical (O’Loughlin, Kolossov and Vendina, 1997; Pavlovskaya and Hanson, 2001). A characteristic opinion is that of Moscow's
chief architect: "Administration in the city center must be represented by
organizations of the federal level, trade must only be available in the form of
leisure, as a big signboard for all to see rather than a street with shops; all housing should be in
the attics" (Domnysheva, 1996). The new business
and political elite have expropriated the rehabilitated areas of center and
this course of development is leading to the establishment of a “super-city”
within Moscow. This
“dual city” is remaking the center as totally different by its contents in the
form of higher-order functions, but it also is acquiring a new post-Soviet
look.
The positive results of world-citification consist
in the provision of new services and utilities, the building of an attractive
image of the city in the world-economy, a growing variety of architectural
forms that are completely different from the mediocre Soviet stereotypes, and
the growing diversified services aimed at accommodating both individuals and
businesses. The main problem of the new
emerging strategy of urban development is to combine the tasks of attracting
investors and improving the investment climate with the social programs,
compensation of the consequences of economic restructuring in the city, and the
growing unemployment. The depth of the
current socio-economic crisis in Russia makes it impossible to shift this burden onto the
shoulders of entrepreneurs. A
fully-fledged program is required that incorporates all the participants of
city life and takes their respective interests into account. Above all lie the
interests of Moscow as a city whose growth is a means for an economic
breakthrough and of reaching the world market for Russia.
Therefore, even though they come under a harsh criticism from the public
for being too costly, ambitious projects like “Manezh Square” (a luxurious shopping complex next to Red Square) and “Moscow City” (a business office complex) are crucial in changing the image of
the city and in attracting foreign capital investments to Russia.
The strategic interests of economic growth
necessitate concentration of resources for the development of the most
promising business improvement districts: not every “busy” street corner or
Metro station may be regarded as a potential business district. Investments are being squandered to the
detriment not only of the urban environment but also of the process of
integration into the world economy. A
special tax for the owners of real estate in the most prestigious business
districts could be introduced so that resources thus generated could be used to
finance social needs. The office boom
should not eclipse the interests of the population as a whole. The most
attractive and prestigious sections of the city must be accessible to the
general public and they should not be turned into citadels for the well-to-do
as has happened in Western cities. Gated
communities with armed guards have made their appearance in the high-prestige Moscow neighborhoods.
As housing facilities become dominated over time by elite housing, the
system of services should include trade and services to accommodate different
strata of the population, including culture and entertainment, trade and
service firms.
Moscow
has now appeared on the lists of world cities after three-quarters of a century
isolated from the capitalist world-economy.
Unlike Western cities, social polarization is happening quickly in Moscow
as the city authorities have been unwilling or unable to tackle the “dual city”
phenomenon that is rapidly developing and is especially visible in the center
and certain key business districts.
While historic buildings are being gentrified to Western standards of
taste and quality, vast tracts of the housing stock in the city are being
allowed to continue to decay. Moscow
is a model for other former Soviet cities.
Its experiences are being repeated in dozens of cities across Russia,
although at a smaller scale and with a sizeable time lag. The entrepreneurial strategy of Mayor Yuri Luzhkov has been successful in centering Moscow
as the link between the Russian economy and the rest of the world economy and
the political support for this strategy still seems solid in the absence of any
credible opposition or alternative model of development. Whether Moscow
ends up more like Rio de Janeiro or
Frankfurt is still an open question but an important one
for the future of Russia
and the world system.
References
300 krupneishikh rossiiskikh bankov (300
Largest Russian Banks).
Profil, 23,
1999: 36-48.
Administrativnye okruga goroda Moskvy v 1998 godu (Administrative Districts of the
City of Moscow in 1998). Moscow: Moskomstat, 1999.
Agnew, John A., “From the Political Economy of Regions to
Regional Political Economy.” Progress
in Human Geography, 24,
1: 101-110, March 2000.
Beaverstock,
Jon V., R.G. Smith and Peter J. Taylor, “A Roster of World Cities.” Cities,
16, 6:445-458, November 1999.
Beaverstock,
Jon V., R.G. Smith, Peter J. Taylor,
David F. Walker and H.N. Lorimer, “Globalization and World Cities: Some Measurement Methodologies.” Applied
Geography, 20, 1: 43-63, January 2000.
Castells, Manuel,
The Informational City: Information Technology,
Economic Restructuring and the Urban-Regional Process. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1989.
Castells, Manuel,
“European Cities, the Informational Society, and the Global Economy” in Leo Deben, Willem Heinemeijer, and
Dick van der Vaart (eds) Understanding
Amsterdam. Amsterdam: Het Spinhuis,
6-23, 1993.
Castells, Manuel,
The Rise of the Network Society. Oxford: Basil Blackwell, 1996.
Claval, Paul,
“Les Capitales: L'heure de
la Metropolisation.”
Planification et Strategies de Développement dans les Capitales Européennes. Christian
Vandermotten, ed. Bruxelles:
Universitée Libre de Bruxelles, p. 21-27, 1994.
Domnysheva, Larisa,
“Novy glavnyi arkhitektor stolitsy Aleksandr Kuzmin o Moskve (New Head of Architecture of the Capital – Alexander
Kuzmin – on Moscow).” Itogi: 61 October 1996.
Fossaert, Ray,
“World Cities in a World System.” Research Bulletin 38.
Loughborough, UK: Globalization and World Cities Study Group and
Network, University of Loughborough, 2001.
Friedmann, John,
“The World City Hypothesis.” Development
and Change, 17, 1:69-83,
January 1986.
Friedmann, John, “Where
We Stand: A Decade of World City Research.” In Paul L. Knox and Peter .J. Taylor (eds) World Cities in a World-System. New
York: Cambridge University Press, p.21-47, 1995.
Gilyarovsky Vladimir, “Moskva i Moskvitchy (Moscow and Moscovites)”. Moscow: Vysshaya shkola, 1980.
Gottmann, Jean & Robert Harper, (eds)
Since Megalopolis. The Urban Writings of
Jean Gottmann. Baltimore, MD:
John Hopkins University Press, 1990.
Graham, Stephen, “Planning for the Telecommunications-Based
City: Experience and Prospects.” European Spatial Research and Policy,
1, 2:21-41, June 1994
Graham, Stephen and G. Dominy,
“Planning for the Information
City: The U.S. Case.” Progress
in Planning, 35, 3:
169-248, 1991
Gritsai, Olga,
“Postindustrialinye sdvigi
v Moscve: kontseptsia "globalnogo goroda" i strukturnaya perestroyka ekonomiki
(Post-industrial shifts in Moscow:
The Concept of the ‘Global City’ and Economic Structural Transformations).” Izvestia RAN (Russian Academy of Sciences), Seria Geograficheskaya, No. 5, pp.90-97, 1996.
Gritsai, Olga, “Moscow under Globalization and
Transition: Paths of Economic Restructuring.” Urban Geography, 18,
2: 155-165, February-March, 1997.
Gubanov, S. “The Moscow Industrial Policy
Model.” Problems of Economic Transition, 42,
4: 5-28, August, 1999.
Hall, Peter G., The World Cities. 3rd edition. New York; McGraw-Hall, 1983
Harvey,
David,
“From Managerialism to Entrepreneurialism: The Transformation
in Urban Governance in Late Capitalism.” Annals, Association of American Geographers, 71,1: 3-17,
March 1989a.
Harvey,
David, The Condition of Postmodernity.
Oxford: Basil
Blackwell, 1989b.
Investitsionnye reitingi rossiikikh regionov, 1998-1999 (Investment
Ratings of Russian Regions, 1998-1999). Expert, 39
(203), 20-44, 1999.
Ioffe, Grigory and Tatyana Nefedova, “Environs
of Russian Cities: The Case Study of Moscow” Europe-Asia
Studies, 50, 8: 1325-1356,
December 1998.
Klimanov, Viktor, “Prolifération des Banques” In
Roger Brunet, Denis Eckert and Vladimir Kolossov (eds.) Atlas de la Russie et de Pays Proches. Paris: Documentation Francaise, pp. 178-179, 1995.
Kolossov, Vladimir. “Political Polarization at the National and
the Intra-Urban Levels: the Role of Moscow in Russian politics and the
Socio-Political Cleavages within the City”. GeoJournal,
42: 4, 385-401, August, 1997.
Kolossov, Vladimir, (ed). Geopoliticheskoe Polozhenie
Rossii: Predstavlenia i realnost (The Geopolitical
Situation of Russia: Representations and Reality). Moscow: Art-Courrier, 2000.
Kolossov, Vladimir and
Olga Vendina “Moscou:
Retour à la Route Mondiale.” In Métropolisation et Politique. Paul Claval, ed. Paris: L'Harmattan, pp. 135-153,
1997.
Knox,
Paul L. and Peter J. Taylor, eds.
World Cities in a World System. New York: Cambridge University Press, 1995.
Lappo, Georgy M., “La Region Metropolitana de Moscu: Particularidades y Problemas.” Estudios Geograficos, no. 204, VII-IX, pp. 24-37, 1992.
Lappo, Georgy M., Grigory A. Golz, and Andrei Treivish,
(eds.) Moskovskii stolichnyi region (Moscow – Capital Region). Moscow: Institute of Geography of the USSR Academy of Sciences, 1988.
Logan, John R. and Harvey Molotch, Urban
Fortunes: The Political Economy of Place. Berkeley, CA:
University of California Press, 1987.
Mallett, William J., “Managing the Post-Industrial City: Business Improvement Districts in the United States.” Area,
26, 3: 276-287, September 1994.
Mollenkopf, John and Manuel Castells, Dual City: Urban Restructuring in
New York. New York: Russell Sage Foundation, 1991.
Moskva: vzgliad v tretie tysyacheletie (novyi generalnyi plan razvitia i ego realizatsia) (Moscow: a View in the Third Millenium:
the New General Plan of Development and Its Realization). Arkhitektura i stroitelstvo Moskvy (Architecture and Construction Works in Moscow), Special Issue, 5-6, 2001.
Nefedova, Tatyana and
Andrei Treivish, Regiony Rossii i drugikh evropeiskikh stran s perekhodnoi ekonomikoi v nachale 90-kh gg. (The Regions of Russia and of other European Countries
in Transition in early 90s.) Moscow: Institute of Geography, Russian Academy of
Sciences -Vash Vybor, 1994
Ognev, Maxim.
“Wanted: Office Space.” Moscow Times Business Review, November 2001. (www.businessreview.ru/stories/33/1.html).
O’Loughlin, John, Between
Stuttgart and Sheffield: Amsterdam in an Integrated Europe and a Competitive
World-Economy. Amsterdam: Amsterdam Study Center for the Metropolitan Environment, 1992.
O’Loughlin,
John and Jürgen Friedrichs, Social
Polarization in Post-Industrial Metropolises. New York and Berlin: De Gruyter, 1996.
O’Loughlin, John, Vladimir Kolossov and Olga Vendina, “The Electoral Geographies of a Polarizing City: Moscow, 1993-1996.” Post-Soviet Geography and Economics, 38, 10: 567-601, December 1997.
Pagonis, Thanos and Andy Thornley, “Urban Development Projects in Moscow: Market/State Relations in the New Russia.” European Planning Studies, 8, 6: 751-766, December 2000.
Pavlovskaya, Marianna and Susan Hanson, “Privatization
of the Urban Fabric: Gender and Local Geographies of Transition in Downtown Moscow.” Urban Geography
22, 1: 4-28,
January-February, 2001.
Ponomarenko, Alexei.
“Gross Regional Product for Russian Regions: Compilation Methods and
Preliminary Results.” In Kimitaka Matsuzato
(ed.) Regions: A Prism to View the
Slavic-Eurasian World - Towards a Discipline of “Regionology”.
Sapporo, Japan: Slavic Research Center, Hokkaido University, pp. 262-277, 2000.
Sassen, Saskia, The Global
City: New York, London, Tokyo. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press, 1991.
Sassen, Saskia, “Paris, Ville Globale.”
Le Debat.
Paris: L'Harmattan, 1993
Sassen, Saskia, “On Concentration and Centrality in the Global
City.” In Paul L. Knox and Peter J. Taylor (eds) World-Cities
in the World-System. New York: Cambridge University Press, pp.
63-78, 1995.
Shakhar, Ari, “The Global Economy and World Cities.” in Ari Shakhar and Sture Öberg, eds.
The World Economy and the Spatial Organisation
of Power. Aldershot, UK: Avebury, pp. 149-160,
1990.
Startseva, Alla, “The Great Race for Retail Space.” Moscow Times, October 22,
2001,
13.
Taylor, Peter J., “World Cities and Territorial States Under Conditions of Contemporary
Globalization.” Political Geography,
19, 1: 5-32, January 2000.
Taylor, Peter J. and
Michael Hoyler, “The Spatial Order of European Cities Under
Conditions of Contemporary Globalization.” Tidjschrift
voor Economische en Sociale Geografie, 91, 2: 176-189, May 2000.
Treivish, Andrei and Tatyana Nefedova. “Novye tendentsii urbanizatsii v Rossii” (New Tendencies of Urbanization in Russia) Problemy prognozirovania
(Problems of Forecasting), No. 5,
158-167, 2000.
Treivish, Andrei, Kavita Pandit, and Andrew R. Bond, “Macrostructural Employment Shifts and Urbanization in the
Former USSR: An International Perspective.” Post-Soviet Geography, 34, 3: 157-171 March 1993.
Vendina, Olga, “Sotsialnoe rassloenie v Moskve: Tsena ekonomicheskikh reform
(Social Differentials in Moscow:
The Price of Economic Reform).” Izvestia RAN
(Russian Academy of Sciences), Seria Geograficheskaya, No. 5: 98-113, 1996.
Vendina, Olga, “Transformation Processes in Moscow: Intra-Urban Stratification of Population.” Geojournal 42, 4:349-363,
August 1997.
Wacquant, Löic, “Urban Outcasts: Stigma and Division in the Black
American Ghetto and the French Urban Periphery.” International Journal of
Urban and Regional Research, 17, 3: 366-383, September 1993.
Wichmann Mathhiessen, Christian. “Scientific Centres in Europe: An Analysis of Research Strength and
Patterns of Specialisation based on Bibliometric Indicators.” Urban Studies, 36, 3: 453-477, March 1999.
Notes
1. Many
of the flights to the Commonwealth of Independent States and of charter flights
do not originate from Sheremetyevo airport but
instead are based at Moscow’s Vnukovo or Domodedovo airports.
2. Moscow banks offer around 80 different kinds of the
banking services, while in Western countries, the
choice of such services is usually in excess of 200.
3. From the
combined indicator of the number of the banks, the traditional district savings
banks, which have become divisions of Sberbank
(Savings bank) are not indicated since their spatial distribution is not
governed by the laws of
banking activity self-organization, but instead by the rules
adopted during Soviet times. At the end of 1996, Moscow Bank of the
Russian Federation Sberbank had 34 divisions in the
capital (roughly corresponding to Moscow’s administrative districts that existed before
1991) and 763 branches. Thus, one branch of the bank serves, on average, 13,000
Muscovites. The bank currently intends
to open 150 more branches so than one branch will serve an average of 10,000
town-dwellers. It should be noted, however, that centripetal trends are crucial
for divisions of Sberbank as well, because their
density in the center is 2-3 times greater than in the new districts in Moscow outskirts.
This is an indirect indication that even Sberbank
intends to serve the "day-time population" of the city.